In some departments of our daily life, in which we imagine ourselves free agents, we are ruled by dictators exercising great power. --Edward Bernays, Propaganda (1928)Centuries ago, when the details of the natural universe were first being worked out with mathematical precision, a mental picture began to emerge in some quarters. Some philosopher-physicists began to believe the universe worked like a fabulously large and complex clock: given knowledge of conditions at any instant, one could take a set of deterministic physical equations and do a
Of course, Bernays recognized limits to propaganda’s powers. Used skillfully it could be a tremendous tool for smoothing out humanity’s rough edges and overcoming our cognitive deficiencies—even turning them to our, collective, advantage. But it can’t lead the mind where it won’t go. Some products just can’t be sold. (Despite some interesting attention paid to political uses of his craft, it’s clear that more than anything Bernays understands propaganda to be lucrative. One of my favorite passages:
Under the old salesmanship the manufacturer said to the prospective purchaser, “Please buy a piano.” The new salesmanship has reversed the process and caused the prospective purchaser to say to the manufacturer, “Please sell me a piano.”The book is, after all, in many ways an advertisement to potential private sector employers of Bernays' skills in the arts of the “new salesmanship.”) Whatever else can be said about his ideas, clearly Bernays’ insight in pinpointing “creating circumstances” as the key to shaping outcomes is critical. It’s an insight that would be echoed in a big way nearly a century later by Richard Thaler and Cass Sunstein (two UChicago scholars, though Sunstein fled for the greener pastures of Harvard a few years ago and currently resides in the Obama administration as Administrator of the Office of Information and Regulatory Affairs), most notably in their 2008 book Nudge. Thaler and Sunstein rebrand Bernays’ essential concept as “choice architecture” and its implementers as “choice architects.” In a very real way, these architects are one important incarnation of the “dictators” Bernays referenced; as he wrote, “We are governed, our minds molded, our tastes formed, our ideas suggested, largely by men we have never heard of.” In Thaler and Sunstein’s telling—in their paper “Choice Architecture”, which is an awesome and highly recommended read if you have a few minutes--“A choice architect has the responsibility for organizing the context in which people make decisions.” These are the circumstance-creators of Bernays’ invisible intellectual dictatorship. If acting deliberately, these architects have enormous power to shape decision-making on a large scale. As Thaler and Sunstein write in that paper:
Norman’s basic lesson is that designers need to keep in mind that the users of their objects are Humans who are confronted every day with myriad choices and cues. The goal of this essay is to develop the same idea for people who create the environments in which we make decisions: choice architects. If you indirectly influence the choices other people make, you have earned the title. Consider the person who designs the menu in a restaurant. The chef will have decided what food will be served, but it is someone else’s job to put those offerings on paper (or blackboard) and there are lots of ways to do this. Should hot starters be in a different category from cold ones? Are pasta dishes a separate category? Within categories, how should dishes be listed? Where should prices be listed? In a world of Econs [T&C’s word for imaginary beings that “reason brilliantly, catalogue huge amounts of information that they can access instantly from their memories, and exercise extraordinary will power”], these details would not matter, but for Humans, nearly everything matters, so choice architects can have considerable power to influence choices. Or to use our preferred language, they can nudge. Of course, choice architects do not always have the best interests of the people they are influencing in mind. The menu designer may want to push profitable items or those about to spoil by printing them in bold print. Wily but malevolent nudgers like pushy mortgage brokers can have devastating effects on the people who are influenced by them. Conscientious choice architects, however, do have capability to self‐consciously construct nudges in an attempt to move people in directions that will make their lives better. And since the choices these choice architects are influencing are going to be made by Humans, they will want their architecture to reflect a good understanding of how humans behave.The importance of “environments in which we make decisions,” the circumstances in which decision-making takes place if you will, is hugely important to the choices people make, utopian conceptions of human beings as enlightened rational calculators aside. The concept of bounded rationality--that men are not calculators, but rather frequently use mental shortcuts and emotional or borderline irrational techniques to aid in decision-making--was introduced by Herbert Simon in the 1950s and is relevant to this picture of how our minds work. But, as it tends to do, my mind strays to a current health policy issue. Earlier this month Consumers Union released a report they developed in conjunction with a communications firm: “Choice Architecture: Design Decisions that Affect Consumers’ Health Plan Choices.” In 2014, under the Affordable Care Act, residents of every state who don’t have health insurance through their job are supposed to have access to new markets called exchanges (technically, customers are supposed to be able to begin shopping for insurance plans on October 1st of next year). Health plans in the exchanges will compete in “tiers” of coverage, based on a calculation of how generous they are—bronze, silver, gold, and platinum are the four levels of coverage that will exist. These standardized levels are intended to make decision-making easier by allowing apples-to-applies comparisons of insurance plans within a given tier of coverage. This, along with new standardized product descriptions, should help to overcome some of the cognitive limitations that become apparent when a person is shopping for a complex financial product like insurance—limitations that insurance companies can and (I assume) do use to their advantage in the current marketplace.
But this report on choice architecture is focused on a particular aspect of the exchanges: what the web-based health plan chooser tools will look like. When you log onto your state’s exchange website (once it exists), you’ll be guided through a smooth, user-friendly process that will help you find a health plan that suits you. But, as the report’s authors note, “Given the number of attributes associated with health plan choices (premium, covered services, provider quality, etc), no website can emphasize all elements of a health plan equally. Tool designers make decisions about what to emphasize and how to frame the elements that they feel are important to consumers, such as health plan cost or quality.” In short, the choice architecture of the chooser tool is going to be very important. In particular, the authors are concerned about the initial set of plan options that will be displayed to the customer shopping for a plan on the exchange website. The importance of default options is something Thaler and Sunstein emphasize in their work because, more often than not, folks gravitate towards the defaults when they make a choice (“For reasons of laziness, fear, and distraction, many people will take whatever option requires the least effort, or the path of least resistance,” T & S write.) From the exchange choice architecture paper:
The study emphasized the choice architecture used to display the initial set of health plan options. The default choice set radically affects consumers’ shopping experiences because once they see the default, they use it as an anchor or baseline for the rest of their selection process. What consumers see first will frame their understanding of the rest of information – in effect, creating a mental model for them. Consumers won’t always know what they aren’t seeing, and the choice architecture conveys implicit and explicit decisions about what is important. Research conducted by PBGH/CalPERS [an existing exchange in California] shows that 93% of the time the default display of information is accepted by consumers with no customization on their part. More than 60% of users of the Checkbook site make their decisions without leaving the initial summary screen.The authors of the Consumers Union report looked at how existing exchange-like tools work (including the existing exchange in Massachusetts) to consider the options available to states as they think about how to display plan choices to customers. The report and the considerations it presents are interesting in and of themselves, but the underlying moral is one laid out by Bernays 80-odd years ago: when folks shop for insurance plans on their state’s exchange website, imagining themselves free agents, they are in fact going to be ruled by dictators whose design decisions greatly affect consumer decisions. If you’re slightly unnerved by the power afforded these invisible, web design dictators, perhaps Bernays’ parting thought—reminding us that propaganda, and thus choice architecture, can be a tool for achieving good and noble aims—is worth noting:
Intelligent men must realize that propaganda is the modern instrument by which they can fight for productive ends and help to bring order out of chaos.Once more unto the breach, dear friends...
No comments:
Post a Comment